alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci economic Growth in england, 1250-1850: some new estimates using a demand side approach 1. Introduction Following the pioneering work of angus maddison (2001; 2003; 2007), economic historians have devoted significant research efforts to the construction of statistical appraisals of the performance of european economies since the end of the middle ages by attempting to work out more and more reliable estimates of GdP per capita. Just to name only a few of the most recent contributions: Broadberry et al. (2011) have produced estimates of GdP per capita for england and Britain over the period 1270- 1870; clark (2010) for england for the period 1200-1870; van Zanden and van leeuwen (2012) for Holland over the period 1347-1807; malanima (2011) for central and northern italy for the period 1300-1913; Álvarez-nogal and Prados de la escosura (2007) for spain and Pfister (2011) for Germany over the period 1500-1850. as all these authors would readily admit, these estimates ought still to be considered as highly conjectural. still one cannot avoid the impression, that these ongoing efforts of statistical reconstructions of GdP per capita have the potential to put our understanding of the patterns of economic growth during the pre-industrial revolution period on a more secure footing. Broadly speaking, so far these contributions have produced two opposed accounts of european economic rivista di storia economica, a. XXiX, n. 1, aprile 2013 We are particularly grateful to Paolo Malanima for very helpful comments and en- couragement. We would like also to thank Greg Clark, Alexia Delfino, Bas van Leeu- wen, Bob Allen, Francisco Beltran Tapia and Florian Ploeckl for useful discussions. Alessandro Nuvolari gratefully acknowledges the Jemolo Fellowship Scheme and the hospitality of Nuffield College, Oxford whilst writing this paper. 32 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci performance in the 1200-1800 period. in a recent paper, clark (2011) has eloquently described these conflicting interpretations as a debate between «malthus» and the «revolt of the early modernists». the malthusian view, which has been fully articulated by clark (2007a), contends that all societies (including england) before the industrial revolution were characterized by a malthusian dynamics. the implication is that in these societies GdP per capita exhibited fluctuations around a subsistence income (defined as the level of income at which birth and death rates are equal), but without any systematic growth trend. the «revolt of the early modernists» interpretation, instead, argues that, since the end of the middle ages, it is possible to discern a small but steady acceleration in the rate of economic growth in at least two european countries: england and the netherlands. 1 the current estimates suggest that the «cruising speed» for these two successful early modern economies was represented by an average compound growth rate of GdP per capita of about 0.2 per cent per year. Broadberry et al. (2011) estimate an average growth rate of GdP per capita of 0.17 per cent per year for england over the period 1270-1690 and van Zanden and van leeuwen (2012, p. 123) reckon an average growth rate 0.19 per cent per year over the period 1347-1807 for Holland. these growth rates of GdP per capita may be seen as broadly consistent (albeit slightly lower) with those emerging from maddison’s comprehensive dataset on the historical development of the world economy (maddison 2007, p. 383: 0.27 per cent for the united Kingdom and 0.28 per cent for the netherlands for the period 1500-1820). interestingly enough, these estimates also resonate well with the early speculative assessment of david landes (1969, pp. 13-14): Western europe was already rich before the industrial revolution [...] it seems clear that over the near millennium from the year 1000 to the eighteenth century, income per head raise appreciably – perhaps tripled and that this rise sharply accelerated in the eighteenth century even before the introduction of the new industrial technology. the present state of the debate can therefore be described as follows: we have two conflicting sets of estimates of GdP per capita for england, one consistent economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 33 with the malthusian view (clark 2010) and one supporting «the revolt of the early modernists» (Broadberry et al. 2011). it should be noted that these estimates of GdP per capita have been reconstructed using two different approaches and different types of data. clark’s estimates are based on an income approach (GdP is computed as the sum of all property incomes plus wages) whereas the estimates of Broadberry et al. (2011) have been constructed using an output approach (GdP is computed as the sum of the outputs of all economic sectors). the next step in the debate seems to be the analysis of the relative compatibility of these estimates with other pieces of empirical evidence. this, for example, is precisely the approach of clark (2011). in this paper, however, we adopt a different and more modest research strategy. We take as starting point the price and wage data that clark (2010) has used for his estimates and we construct a new time series of GdP per capita for england over the period 1250-1850 using an alternative (indirect) method: the demand side approach. this approach has been effectively used by malanima (2011) for constructing estimates of GdP per capita for central and northern italy. our aim is to check the consistency of clark (2010) and Broadberry et al. (2011) series of per capita GdP with new estimates constructed using a different approach with the hope to contribute to their further refinement. since the patterns underlying the GdP per capita series of clark (2010) and Broadberry et al. (2011) are so strikingly divergent, it seems appropriate to provide a preliminary assessment of these contributions by reconstructing a new series of GdP per capita for england employing an alternative method. the remaining of the paper is structured as follows. in the next section we introduce the demand side method for estimating GdP per capita and we discuss its main advantages and limitations. subsequently, we describe the data and sources we have used. in section 3 we set out our estimates and compare them with those of Broadberry et al. (2011) and clark (2010). section 4 concludes. 34 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci 2. Methods and Materials 2.1. The Demand Side Approach our approach to the estimation of GdP per capita follows the one developed by malanima (2011) for central and northern italy. the approach is based on a two-step procedure. the first step consists in the estimation of the output of the agricultural sector using the demand-side method. this method has been used, among others, by allen (2000) and Federico and malanima (2004) for constructing estimates of agricultural output in the early modern period respectively for a number of european countries and for italy. the starting point is the following equation defining total agricultural output (YA): (1) YA = r · c · N In equation (1) r C Y A A= is the ratio of domestic agricultural production (YA) to agricultural consumption (CA) in the country in question (if r = 1 the trade position of the country in agricultural goods is perfectly balanced), c N CA= is the consumption per capita of agricultural goods and N is the total population. dividing both sides of equation (1) by N we get per capita agricultural output yA: (2) yA = r · c next, we assume that per capita consumption of agricultural goods c will depend on the level of wages and prices according to the following equation (allen 2000, p. 13; Federico and malanima 2004, p. 438): (3) c W P Pa m$ $= a b c equation (2) is a demand function where W is the real wage, Pa a price index of agricultural products, Pm a price index of manufactures and a, b and c are the (constant) elasticities of demand of agricultural products with respect to wages and prices. standard microeconomic consumer theory suggests that a + b + c = 0 (malanima 2011, p. 171). By making sensible assumptions on the magnitudes of the economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 35 elasticity coefficients, a, b and c, and using the available data on wages and prices it is possible to get an estimate of c, and from there, after having made an evaluation of r, it is possible to obtain the value of the per capita agricultural output yA. the second step of the procedure consists in using the estimated values of per capita agricultural output to get to an estimate of real GdP per capita. in order to do this, it is necessary to formulate an assessment of the share of total agricultural output in aggregate GdP. in the case of italy, malanima (2011) estimates the share of agriculture output in total production using two different approaches. the first method is based on the extrapolation of the share of output in the secondary and tertiary sectors from urbanization levels on the basis of the results of a regression equation relating the share of output in the secondary and tertiary sectors to urbanization levels in post unification italy. the second approach consists in a backward extrapolation of the non- agricultural output share for the period 1851-1860 using the trend displayed by the share of non-agricultural employment in the total working population. this second method relies on the assumption that the relative labour productivity in agriculture compared to that of the rest of the economy did not change. Here, we adopt a more simple procedure. We define the share of agricultural output in total output (Y) as (4) S Y Y A A= equation (4) can be written as: (5) S L L A A A $ $ r r = where LA is the numbers of workers in agriculture, L is the total number of workers in the economy, L Y A A Ar = and L Y r = represent respectively the labour productivity of agriculture and of the entire economy, measured in terms of output per worker. if we assume competitive labour markets, real wages in agriculture p wAc m and in the entire economy p wc m will track closely labour productivity. 2 We can then 36 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci use the ratio of real wages between the two sectors as a proxy for the relative productivity of agriculture with the respect to the entire economy p w p wA A, r r c m. in other words, equation (5) is transformed into (6) S p w L p w L A A A $ $ = using equation (6) we can estimate SA provided that we have data on real wages in agriculture and in the total economy and the share of working population employed in the agricultural sector L LAc m. it is worth noting, that the main difference between our approach and that of malanima (2011) is that rather than assuming a constant level of relative labour productivity between agriculture and the rest of the economy, we have preferred to make the assumption of (nearly) competitive labour markets. We shall adopt this method for estimating the share of agriculture in total output only for the period before 1690. For the more recent period, instead we shall base our assessment on other existing estimates. once we have estimated agricultural output per capita and the share of agriculture in aggregate output, we can calculate per capita GdP (y) using the formula: (7) y N Y S y A A= = clearly, the demand side approach is an indirect method of estimating agricultural output and GdP. compared to the more conventional and «direct» output and income approaches, the main advantage of the demand side approach is represented by being less exacting in terms of the data necessary for constructing the estimates (as we have seen, the data needed for implementing the approach are time series of wages and prices). the main limitation of the approach is the need of relying on a number of rather stringent assumptions both for the computation of per capita agricultural consumption and of the share of agriculture in total income. it is also important to note that the geographical scope of the estimates constructed with this method will reflect the geographical scope of the original time series of wages and prices employed. economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 37 2.2. Data and Sources the average wage and the farm wage time series we employ are derived from clark (2010, pp. 54-55). these wage time series are based, in turn, on clark (2007b) for farm wages and clark (2005) for non-farm wages. Farm and non-farm wages are then weighted by their respective employment share to compute an aggregate average wage series (clark 2010). all these series are for daily wages and they are constructed as 10-year averages. real wages are computed using the cost of living index proposed by clark (clark 2010, pp. 98-99). the estimation of per capita agricultural output (equation 3) is based on two time series of prices: agricultural goods and manufactures. the price index of manufactured goods is a geometric index constructed by clark (2010, pp. 138-139) using as weights the expenditure shares and it covers the prices of products such as: pottery, glass, woodware, pewter goods, brass goods, cutlery, paper, etc. the price index of agricultural goods is derived from clark (2004). it is also a geometric index employing output shares as weights and comprising the price series of 26 products: wheat, barley, oats, rye, peas, beans, potatoes, hops, straw, mustard seed, saffron, hay, beef, mutton, pork, bacon, tallow, eggs, milk, cheese, butter, wool, firewood, timber, cider and honey. the index has been constructed by aggregating these individual series in four main categories: arable products, pastoral products, wood products and cider/honey. these four main sub-components are then aggregated into a composite index of agricultural products. also these series represent 10-year averages. since we are interested in relative prices, both price series of agricultural products and manufactures have been deflated using the cost of living index constructed by clark (2010, pp. 98-99). the data on the share of agricultural workers in the total working population L LAc m are taken from allen (2000, p. 8). allen constructs this estimate of the distribution of the labour force following the method originally developed by Wrigley (1985). this approach consists in assessing the size of population engaged in non-agricultural occupations on the basis of the rates of urbanization. this estimate is then adjusted in order to take into account the share of rural population engaged in non-agricultural occupations (allen 38 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci 2000, pp. 4-13). allen provides estimates for the following years: 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800. clark (2010, pp. 56-57) has also recently reconstructed alternative estimates of the share of employment in agriculture. Figure 1 compares allen and clark’s estimates. Figure 1 shows that clark’s estimates for the period before 1700 are much lower than those of allen’s. in this paper, we use allen’s estimates as they seem to be consistent with those elaborated independently by crafts using the social tables for 1688 and 1759 (crafts 1985, p. 14). Furthermore, in the italian case, malanima has also found allen’s estimates of the employment structure for the period 1300-1800 fairly plausible and consistent with other pieces of empirical evidence (malanima 2011, p. 184). using allen’s estimates of the employment share in agriculture, we can estimate the share of agriculture in total output using equation (6) for the benchmark years 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1750 and 1800. We calculate the intervening values between these benchmark estimates by interpolation. in this way, we are able to construct a complete time series of the agricultural share in total output. to check the reliability of our estimates, in figure 2 we compare them with alternative estimates of the agricultural share in total output constructed by deane and cole (1969, p. 156 for the years 1688 and 1770 and p. 166 for the period after 1800-1850) and crafts (1985, p. 16 for the period 1690-1760; p. 45 for the period 1780-1801 and the period 1801-1831 and crafts, 1983, p. 191 for the year 1780). We FIgure 1. employment share in agriculture, 1300-1850. 0.85 0.75 0.65 0.55 0.45 0.35 0.25A gr ic ul tu ra l e m pl oy m en t s ha re 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 Clark Allen Crafts economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 39 should note that these estimates of the sectoral share of agriculture developed by crafts have been employed also for the construction of the revised estimates of real GdP growth proposed by crafts and Harley (1992, p. 715). in figure 2 the series labeled «ricci-nuvolari» represents our estimation of the share of agriculture in total output computed using equation (6) whereas the series labelled «deane & cole» and «crafts» represent deane and cole and crafts estimates. Figure 2 shows that our estimates for the early years 1690-1700 are fully in line with those proposed by crafts and deane and cole (in particular our calculation using equation (6) yields an estimate of the agricultural share in total output in 1700 of 36 per cent while crafts considers this to be 37 per cent). For the period after 1700 instead the decline of the agricultural share in total output computed using equation (6) is more rapid than that shown in crafts and deane and cole estimates. allen (2009) has argued that in the period 1770-1840 real wages stagnated whereas output per worker increased: a prolonged divergence leading to a significant shift in income distribution. clearly, this means that estimating the agricultural output share using equation (6) is not likely to be an accurate procedure for this historical period. For this reason we have decided to revise our estimates for the interval 1700-1850 adopting a series closer to the estimates of crafts and deane and cole which are based on more direct assessments of the nominal value of output in different sectors in benchmark FIgure 2. agriculture share in total output, 1690-1850. 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0A gr ic ul tu ra l s ha re in to ta l o ut pu t 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 Crafts Deane & Cole Ricci & Nuvolari Ricci & Nuvolari amended (1700-1850) 40 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci years. in particular, we have used the following procedure. We adopt as a «compromise» estimate of the agricultural share in total output in 1800 the average of the crafts and deane and cole estimates. then we compute the new estimates for the period 1700-1800 by interpolation between the value of our time series in 1700 and the new value of 1800. For the interval 1800-1830, we construct our estimates by interpolation between our new value of 1800 and the value for 1830 estimated by deane and cole. Finally the observations for 1840 and 1850 are derived directly from the deane and cole estimations. in this way we obtain a new series of agricultural share for the period 1700-1850 which in figure 2 is labeled as «ricci-nuvolari amended (1700- 1850)». to sum up, our final estimates of the agricultural share in total output are represented by the «ricci-nuvolari» series for the period before 1700 and by the «ricci-nuvolari amended» series for the period after 1700. the data on the ratio between agricultural production and the domestic consumption of agricultural goods (r) are taken from crafts (1985, p. 127) for the period 1800-1850. intervening values were obtained by interpolation. We should note that alternative estimates provided by thomas (1985, p. 148) are also available for the period 1800-1850. However, they are very close to those proposed by crafts. For the period before 1700, there are no sources of data readily available. However, according to allen (2000, p. 14), «[t]here is no indication that r differed from one before the middle of the seventeenth century». Here we follow the same type of assumption and consider r = 1 up to the year 1750. 3 values for the period 1750-1800 were computed by interpolation. the price and income elasticities of the demand function (3) are taken from allen (2000, p. 14). allen, on the basis of studies of modern developing countries, assumes the demand elasticity with the respect to the price of manufactures (Y) to be equal to 0.1. the demand elasticity with respect to the price of agricultural goods (b) is taken to be –0.6. as a result, the condition a + b + c = 0, suggests that a must be equal to 0.5. experiments with alternative values of these elasticities have produced very similar estimates of agricultural output. 4 Finally the data on population are taken from Wrigley and schofield (1997) for the period after 1541. For the previous period the data are taken from clark (2010, pp. 64-65). economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 41 3. Estimating Agricultural Output and GDP Per Capita the complete time series of our estimates of per capita agricultural output and of real per capita GdP calculated using the procedures explained in the previous section are presented in the appendix. Figure 3 shows our estimates of per capita agricultural output (yA) and of total agricultural output (YA). total agricultural output has been computed by multiplying per capita agricultural output by total population. all these estimates are reported using the index 1700 = 100. Figure 4 compares our estimates of total agricultural output with those of allen (2000) and Broadberry et al. (2011). the estimates of Broadberry et al. (2011) refer to england in the period 1270-1700 and to Great Britain for the period 1700-1850. our estimates appear to be in broad agreement with those of allen (2000). For the period before 1550, the estimates of agricultural output of Broadberry et al. (2011) are instead somewhat lower. the implication is that these estimates will display faster growth throughout this period. For the period after 1550-1750, our estimates and those of allen (2000) and of Broadberry et al. (2011) appear to be broadly consistent. taking into account that our estimates have been constructed following the same approach used by allen (the only difference are the wages and prices series used in the computation), these findings are not completely surprising. the obvious implication is that a possible avenue for further research will be to search for the factors accounting for this divergence in agricultural output estimates between the output and the demand side approach in the period before 1600. Figure 5 contains our estimates of GdP per capita compared with those of clark (2010), Broadberry et al. (2011), maddison (2001, p. 247) and malanima (2011, p. 189). again, all the series are reported using the index 1700 = 100. it is important to take into account that maddison’s estimates refer to england, scotland and Wales, the estimates by Broadberry et al. (2011) refer to england for the period 1270-1700 and to Great Britain for the period 1700-1850, while the estimates of all the other authors concern only england. the yearly series of Broadberry et al. (2011) has been converted into 10-year averages centered on each decade (so that it is directly comparable with clark’s and our estimates). overall, our estimates display a pattern that seems to be an intermediate case between the estimates 42 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci FIgure 3. agricultural output (1700 = 100). 300 250 200 150 100 50 0A gr ic ul tu ra l o ut pu t ( 17 00 = 1 00 ) 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 18501300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1800 Per capita agricultural output Total agricultural output FIgure 4. comparative estimates of total agricultural output (1700 = 100). 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0A gr ic ul tu ra l o ut pu t ( 17 00 = 1 00 ) 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 Ricci & NuvolariBroadberry et al. Allen FIgure 5. comparative estimates of per capita GdP (1700 = 100). 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 P er c ap ita G dp (1 70 0 = 1 00 ) 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 Ricci & NuvolariClark Maddison Broadberry et al. Malanima economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 43 proposed by clark (2010) and those of Broadberry et al. (2011). the different patterns of economic growth implicit in these time series estimations become apparent when we consider long run growth rates. table 1 compares the average compound growth rates of GdP per capita of the different estimates using various subperiods. We have also included in the table the estimates of crafts and Harley (crafts and Harley 1992; Harley 1993, p. 178) covering the years 1700-1830. For the period 1250-1580, our estimates are consistent with those of clark showing no positive growth. in particular, as it can be seen from figure 5, both our estimates and those of clark exhibit a large «malthusian cycle» of growth and decline beginning around 1300 and ending around 1600 (although the cycle is clearly more nuanced in our estimates than in clark’s). the peak of the cycle occurs around 1450. this behavior of GdP per capita mirrors the fluctuations of the real wage series constructed by clark (2007a, p. 41). For the interval 1580-1780, our estimates are instead consistent with those of Broadberry et al. (2011) indicating that the english economy was able to attain an annual growth rate of about 0.2 per cent. Hence our estimates suggest that by the end of the sixteenth century the english economy was probably already beginning to break away from the malthusian constraints. 5 this is in contrast with the estimates of clark (2010) showing the english economy attaining a «sizable» positive rate of economic growth only from the end of the eighteenth century. thus, in terms of the overall pattern, our estimates appear consistent with those of Broadberry et al. (2011), suggesting the historical relevance of a three-stages periodization, rather than the two-stage one underlying clark’s estimates. in particular, our estimates show that the period 1250-1580 can be characterized as a «malthusian-phase» with a generalized stagnation in GdP per capita; the period 1580-1780 can be perhaps seen as a «smithian-phase» of positive economic growth preceding the industrial revolution (although we should also note that our estimates of the rate of economic growth during this period are somewhat lower than those of Broadberry et al. (2011)). Finally, all estimated time series are in broad agreement in indicating that the beginning of the process of «modern economic growth» with steady positive growth rates significantly above the threshold of 0.2 per cent per 44 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci year should be probably located at the end of the eighteenth century. interestingly enough, we can note in figure 5 that both the clark’s series and, to a more significant extent, our series suggest a phase of relatively sluggish growth performance in the period of the revolutionary and napoleonic wars (1790- 1810). this is probably to be ascribed to the disrupting effects of the wars on prices. of course since the approach adopted here is relying heavily on the wages and prices series, the erratic behavior of prices in this historical phase may introduce some spurious effects in our estimates for this specific period. Figure 6 contains our estimates of GdP per capita measured in 1990 «Geary-Khamis» PPP dollars, which is the unit of measurement adopted by maddison (2001, 2003, 2007) and it is frequently used for international comparisons. this series has been computed projecting backwards maddison’s value of GdP per capita in england, Wales and scotland for the year 1850 (maddison 2001, p. 247) using our estimated time series of per capita GdP. 6 in order to put our estimates in a comparative context, in figure 6 we have also plotted the series of GdP per capita (also expressed in 1990 PPP $) estimated by malanima (2011). in order to be fully comparable with our series, the yearly series of malanima has been converted into 10-year averages centered on each decade. as we have mentioned, also malanima has constructed his estimates using a very similar approach to the one adopted here. there are two Table 1. Rates of growth of GDP per capita (annual average compound growth rates (%) Period Broadberry et al. clark maddison malanima crafts & Harley ricci & nuvolari 1250-1580 0.12* –0.01 –0.02 1580-1780 0.29 0.03 0.22 1780-1850 0.53 0.51 0.36 1780-1820 0.24 0.46 0.12 1500-1700 0.19 –0.11 0.28 0.14 0.05 1700-1820 0.25 0.21 0.26 0.21 1700-1800 0.06 0.10 1820-1850 0.91 0.57 1.05 0.68 1800-1870 0.79 1700-1780 0.26 0.09 0.24 0.25 1780-1830 0.32 0.46 0.45 0.33 * 1270-1580. economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 45 points of interest arising from figure 6. the first point is that our estimates show that england throughout the late middle ages and very early modern period was considerably richer than the picture emerging from maddison’s estimates. our estimates suggest that over the period 1250-1500 income per capita fluctuated in an interval ranging from a minimum of about 1.000 $ to a maximum of about 1.700 $, whereas maddison reckoned GdP per capita in england to be 400 $ in year 1000 and 762 $ in year 1500. in fact, several authors (Federico 2002; clark 2009) have argued that the basic «subsistence» income level of 400 $ per capita that maddison considers as characteristic of not particularly sophisticated societies is far too low. Following this cue, lo cascio and malanima (2009), on the basis of a number of considerations concerning the price of foodstuffs, clothing and fuel and the level of real wages, have proposed that 700 $ and not 400 $ should be regarded as the minimal «bare bones» threshold for GdP per capita in pre-modern europe. in this perspective, we can see that in figure 6 in the period 1250-1580, english per capita GdP is fluctuating in a range comprised between 1.5 and 2 times this basic level identified by lo cascio and malanima. We should also note that the GdP per capita level estimated by Broadberry et al. (2011) for the period 1250-1350 seems to fluctuate around the minimum «bare bones» threshold of 700 $. the second point that is worth noting is that, even if our estimates show a relative high level of income per capita for england in the period 1250-1600, they still indicate the FIgure 6. GdP per capita in england and in central/northern italy (1990 $), 1250- 1850. 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 G D P p er c ap ita (1 99 0$ ) 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 18501300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1800 England (Ricci & Nuvolari) Italy CN (Malanima) 46 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci existence of a noticeable gap in GdP per capita between italy and england lasting at least until the second half of the fifteenth century. Figure 6 shows that the moment in which england is decidedly overtaking italy is the second half of the seventeenth century. this may perhaps be seen as consistent with interpretations that have pointed to the importance of international trade (in particular the successful challenge mounted by english traders to italian producers in wool textiles during the seventeenth century) in accounting for the patterns of economic divergence in early modern europe (allen 2002). 7 Finally, it is possible to provide a rough assessment of the reliability of our estimates of GdP per capita, by computing the implied number of working days during the year that are «implicit» in our estimates of GdP per capita. Formally the number of working days during the year (d) is equal to: (8) d w L GDP $ $ v = where GdP is the nominal GdP, v the share of wages in total income, w the nominal wage and L the total number of workers. equation (8) tells us how many days it is necessary to work in order to obtain an yearly earning corresponding to a certain level of GdP per capita (given the prevailing wage and patterns of income distribution). in order to implement empirically the formula we proceed as follows. First, we construct an index of nominal GdP by multiplying our estimates of real GdP per capita by the cost of living index constructed by clark (2010, pp. 98-99) and by total population, again taken from clark (2010, pp. 64-65) and Wrigley and schofield (1997). then, following clark (2010, p. 59) we assume that the nominal value of the labour share in total income around 1860 is equal to 420 millions of pounds. 8 We project backwards this estimate of the nominal value of the labour share in total income using the index of nominal GdP and assuming v to be equal to 0.6. this value for v is consistent with the dynamics of the labour share in total income emerging from clark’s estimates (2010, pp. 81-82). in this way, we are able to construct a time-series of the nominal value of labour income (the numerator of formula 8). in order to estimate L we compute the share of working population in total population by dividing the total working population given by deane and cole (1969, p. 143) for the period 1801-1861 by total population economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 47 (clark 2010, p. 65). For the period 1801-1861 we obtain an average value of 0.53. We use this value for calculating the number of workers in each period. We can now compute the denominator of formula (8) by multiplying the average daily wages (series taken from clark (2010, pp. 54-55)) by the total number of workers. Figure 7 compares the number working days during the year computed using equation (8) (the series is labeled «implied working days»), with a number of independent estimates of the actual working year for different periods assembled by allen and Weisdorf (2011). the original sources for these estimates are Blanchard (1978), clark and van der Werf (1998) and voth (2001). overall, figure 6 suggest that our estimates of the working days during the year implicit in our GdP per capita series are able to track rather closely the available independent estimation of working days. Given the admittedly crude procedures adopted for the computation of the working days, we consider this result as a promising preliminary corroboration of our GdP per capita estimates. 4. Conclusions In this paper we have presented a new set of estimates of agricultural per capita output and real per capita GdP for FIgure 7. number of working days implied by ricci-nuvolari GdP per capita es- timates, 1250-1850. 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 N um be r of w or ki ng d ay s 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 Implied working days Blanchard Voth (farmers) Voth (non farmers) Clark & van der Werf 48 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci the english economy in the period 1250-1850 constructed using the demand side approach. as we have seen, this approach to the statistical reconstruction of per capita GdP relies on a number of exacting assumptions and we believe that it should be regarded as nothing more than an useful framework of inquiry for formulating reasoned conjectural assessments of the historical performance of an economy. still, we think that in the case in question, despite its inherent limitations, the implementation of the demand approach has performed reasonably well, generating some interesting findings and producing a rather plausible picture of the long run evolution of the english economy. Further, our estimates have received some further corroboration by being consistent with some empirical evidence concerning the number of working days in the year at different time periods. our estimates suggest that the growth experience of english economy over the period 1250-1850 can be suitably interpreted using a three-stage account. in particular, our estimates indicate the existence of a malthusian phase covering the period 1250-1580. this phase is followed by an «intermediate» stage preceding the industrial revolution covering the seventeenth and eighteenth century during which the economy is able to dissipate some of the malthusian constraints and attain a sustained positive growth rate. the third phase corresponds to the industrial revolution and by a further significant acceleration in the rate of economic growth. in this perspective, the pattern of economic growth underlying our estimates appears broadly consistent with the «revolt of the early modernists» view. However, it is important to take into account that our estimates also provide three important qualifications to this interpretation. the first is that the malthusian phase of generalized stagnation is protracted well after the end of the middle ages lasting approximately until the end of the sixteenth century. the second is that the rate of economic growth reached after the conclusion of the malthusian phase is somewhat lower than that emerging from the ongoing statistical reconstructions based on the output approach (Broadberry et al. 2011). the third is that the levels of GdP per capita during the late middle ages (1250-1400) estimated with the output approach by Broadberry et al. (2011) may be too low. sant’anna school of advanced studies, Pisa economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 49 Table a1. Per capita agricultural output and per capita GDP in England, 1250-1850 Year Per capita agricultural output (1700 = 100) Per capita GdP (1700 = 100) 1250 111.10 83.92 1260 102.57 77.47 1270 87.47 66.07 1280 84.09 63.52 1290 89.29 67.45 1300 87.29 65.93 1310 87.56 65.15 1320 77.83 56.20 1330 89.87 63.03 1340 96.36 65.70 1350 114.06 75.65 1360 113.51 73.30 1370 113.03 71.10 1380 122.60 75.19 1390 129.12 77.25 1400 128.28 83.37 1410 131.12 85.42 1420 132.28 86.38 1430 136.18 89.14 1440 136.65 89.66 1450 146.65 96.46 1460 144.45 95.24 1470 142.03 93.87 1480 137.37 91.01 1490 142.65 94.73 1500 136.20 90.67 1510 138.01 92.52 1520 126.38 85.33 1530 115.83 78.76 1540 128.56 88.04 1550 119.54 82.44 1560 108.65 75.47 1570 118.05 82.57 1580 112.56 79.29 1590 103.37 73.33 1600 93.00 66.45 1610 92.38 68.41 1620 92.41 70.92 1630 92.04 73.21 1640 92.87 76.56 1650 93.21 79.64 1660 97.60 86.43 1670 102.95 94.48 1680 100.88 95.96 1690 105.78 104.29 1700 100.00 100 1710 106.75 109.91 1720 109.52 116.10 Appendix 50 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci Table a1. (continued) Year Per capita agricultural output (1700 = 100) Per capita GdP (1700 = 100) 1730 111.22 121.39 1740 113.37 127.40 1750 114.57 132.56 1760 108.44 129.18 1770 97.40 119.47 1780 96.68 122.09 1790 95.43 124.09 1800 85.99 110.66 1810 83.23 114.72 1820 86.92 128.31 1830 90.86 143.66 1840 91.88 155.60 1850 86.61 157.09 1 the label «revolt of the early modernists» for this interpretation of the dyna- mics of growth in preindustrial europe is due to J. de vries, «the industrial revolution and the industrious revolution», Journal of Economic History, vol. 54, 1994, pp. 249-270. the term was meant to define a new perspective chal- lenging the traditional belief of the european economy before the industrial re- volution as an inherently stagnating, growthless system, see e. leroy ladurie, «motionless History», Social Science History, vol. 1, 1977, pp. 115-136. For an insightful discussion of this view in the case of the netherlands, see J.l. van Zanden, «the ‘revolt of the early modernists’ and the ‘First modern eco- nomy’: an assessment», Economic History Review, vol. 55, 2002, pp. 619-641. 2 this assumption is also made in some recent formal models of pre-industrial european economies, see for example P. sharp, H. strulik, J. Weisdorf, «the determinants of income in a malthusian equilibrium», Journal of Development Economics, vol. 97, 2012, pp. 112-117, and n. voigtlander, H.J. voth, «the th- ree Horsemen of riches. Plague, War, urbanization in early modern europe», mimeo, 2011, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_ id=1029347&http://www.econ.upf.edu/~voth/working_papers.html. 3 For the period 1700-1750 the assumption of r = 1 is based on the consideration that england was a net exporter of corn and an importer of exotic foodstuffs such as sugar, coffee and tea. overall the balance of this segment of trade ap- pears to have been as roughly in equilibrium, see r. davis, «english Foreign trade 1700-1774», Economic History Review, vol. 15, 1962, pp. 285-303. 4 Following P. malanima, «the long decline of a leading economy: GdP in central and northern italy, 1300-1913», European Review of Economic History, vol. 15, 2011, p. 179, we have experimented with values of b rang ing from –0.3 to –0.7 and values of a ranging from 0.2 and 0.6 (with c = 0.1). 5 it is worth noting that our estimates are consistent with Wriglely’s view who considers the late sixteenth century as a fundamental turning point marking the emergence in england of an «advanced organic economy» leading to an accele- ration in the rate of economic growth lasting throughout the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries: e.a. Wrigley, Poverty, Progress and Population, cambridge, cambridge university Press, 2004, pp. 44-67. 6 maddison does not provide an estimate for 1850, so the value for 1850 has been computed assuming a constant growth rate between the 1820 and 1870 observations. economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 51 7 For a perceptive analysis of england’s «forging ahead» and italy’s «falling be- hind» in this historical phase, see P. malanima, «la perdita del primato», Rivi- sta di Storia Economica, vol. 13, 1997, pp. 131-172. 8 this estimate is actually based on l. levi, Wages and Earnings of the Working Classes, london, John murray, 1867. References r.c. allen, «economic structure and agricultural Productivity in europe, 1300-1800», European Review of Economic History, vol. 3, 2000, pp. 1-25. r.c. allen, «Poverty and Progress in early modern europe», Eco- nomic History Review, vol. 56, 2003, pp. 403-443. r.c. allen, «engel’s Pause: technical change, capital accumula- tion and inequality during the British industrial revolution», Explorations in Economic History, vol. 46, 2009, pp. 418-435. r.c. allen, J. Weisdorf, «Was there an ‘industrious revolution’ before the industrial revolution? an empirical exercise for england, 1300-1800», Economic History Review, vol. 64, 2011, pp. 715-729. c. Álvarez-nogal, l. Prados de la escosura, «the decline of spain (1500-1800): conjectural estimates», European Review of Economic History, vol. 11, 2007, pp. 319-366. i. Blanchard, «labour Productivity and Work Psychology in the english mining industry, 1400-1600», Economic History Review, vol. 31, 1978, pp. 1-24. s. Broadberry, B. campbell, a. Klein, m. overton, B. van leeu- wen, «British economic Growth, 1270-1870: an output Based approach», 2011, available at http://www2.lse.ac.uk/economic- History/pdf/Broadberry/BritishGdPlongrun16a.pdf. G. clark, «the Price History of english agriculture, 1209-1914», Research in Economic History, vol. 22, 2004, pp. 41-123. G. clark, «the condition of the Working class in england, 1209- 2004», Journal of Political Economy, vol. 113, 2005, pp. 1307- 1340. G. clark, A Farewell to Alms, Princeton, Princeton university Press, 2007a. G. clark, «the long march of History: Farm Wages, Population and economic Growth in england, 1209-1869», Economic Hi- story Review, vol. 60, 2007b, pp. 97-139. G. clark, «a review of angus maddison’s contours of the World economy, 1-2030 ad», Journal of Economic History, vol. 69, 2009, pp. 1156-1160. 52 alessandro nuvolari and mattia ricci G. clark, «the macroeconomic aggregates for england, 1209- 2008», Research in Economic History, vol. 27, 2010, pp. 51-140. G. clark, «malthus versus ‘the revolt of the early modernists’: european Growth 1200-1800», paper presented at the 9th eu- ropean Historical economics society conference, dublin, 2011, mimeo. G. clark, Y. van der Werf, «Work in Progress? the industrious revolution», Journal of Economic History, vol. 58, 1998, pp. 830-843. n. crafts, «British economic Growth: a review of the evidence», Economic History Review, vol. 36, 1983, pp. 177-199. n. crafts, British Economic Growth During the Industrial Revolu- tion, oxford, clarendon, 1985. n. crafts, K. Harley, «output Growth and the British industrial revolution: a restatement of the crafts-Harley view», Econo- mic History Review, vol. 45, 1992, pp. 703-730. r. davis, «english Foreign trade 1700-1774», Economic History Review, vol. 15, 1962, pp. 285-303. P. deane, m. cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959, cam- bridge, cambridge university Press, 2nd edition, 1969. J. de vries, «the industrial revolution and the industrious revo- lution», Journal of Economic History, vol. 54, 1994, pp. 249-270. G. Federico, «the World economy 0-2000 ad: a review arti- cle», European Review of Economic History, vol. 6, 2002, pp. 111-120. G. Federico, P. malanima, «Progress, decline, Growth: Product and Productivity in italian agriculture, 1000-2000», Economic History Review, vol. 57, 2004, pp. 437-464. K. Harley, «reassessing the industrial revolution: a macro view» in J. mokyr (ed.), The British Industrial Revolution. An Econo- mic Perspective, Boulder, Westview, 1993, pp. 160-205. d.s. landes, The Unbound Prometheus, cambridge, cambridge university Press, 1969. e. leroy ladurie, «motionless History», Social Science History, vol. 1, 1977, pp. 115-136. l. levi, Wages and Earnings of the Working Classes, london, John murray, 1867. e. lo cascio, P. malanima, «GdP in Pre-modern agrarian eco- nomies (1-1820 ad). a revision of the estimates», Rivista di Storia Economica, vol. 25, 2009, pp. 391-419. a. maddison, The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective, Paris, oecd, 2001. a. maddison, The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris, oecd, 2003. a. maddison, Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD, ox- ford, oxford university Press, 2007. economic Growth in england, 1250-1850 53 P. malanima, «la perdita del primato», Rivista di Storia Econo- mica, vol. 13, 1997, pp. 131-172. P. malanima, «the long decline of a leading economy: GdP in central and northern italy, 1300-1913», European Review of Economic History, vol. 15, 2011, pp. 169-219. u. Pfister, «economic Growth in Germany, 1500-1850», mimeo, 2011. P. sharp, H. strulik, J. Weisdorf, «the determinants of income in a malthusian equilibrium», Journal of Development Economics, vol. 97, 2012, pp. 112-117. B. thomas, «Food supply in the united Kingdom during the in- dustrial revolution», in J. mokyr (ed.), The Economics of the Industrial Revolution, new York, rowman & littlefield, 1985, pp. 138-150. J.l. van Zanden, «the ‘revolt of the early modernists’ and the ‘First modern economy’: an assessment», Economic History Review, vol. 55, 2002, pp. 619-641. J.l. van Zanden, B. van leeuwen, «Persistent but not consistent: the Growth of national income in Holland 1347-1807», Explo- rations in Economic History, vol. 49, 2012, pp. 119-130. n. voigtlander, H.J. voth, «the three Horsemen of riches. Pla- gue, War, urbanization in early modern europe», mimeo, 2011, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_ id=1029347&http://www.econ.upf.edu/~voth/working_papers. html. H.J. voth, «the longest Years: new estimates of labour input in england, 1760-1830», Journal of Economic History, vol. 61, 2001, pp. 1065-1082. e.a. Wrigley, «urban Growth and agricultural change: england and the continent in the early modern Period», Journal of Inter disciplinary History, vol. 15, 1985, pp. 638-728. e.a. Wrigley, Poverty, Progress and Population, cambridge, cam- bridge university Press, 2004. e.a. Wrigley, r. schofield., English Population History from Family Reconstruction, cambridge, cambridge university Press, 1997.